F. William Engdahl
The Three Pillars of the British Empire
The Empire Needs a New Strategy
No other element has shaped the history of the past
one hundred years so much as the fight to secure and control the world's reserves
of petroleum. Too little is understood of how political and economic power
around the raw material, petroleum, has been shaped by interests principally
under the control of two governments--England and, later, the United States of
America.
Britain, approaching the end of the 1890's, was in all
respects, the pre-eminent political, military and economic power in the world.
British gold, under the jealous, guarding eye of the
Bank of England, was the basis for the role of the Pound Sterling as the source
spring of world credit, since 1815. Prussian military superiority was the
actual key to the defeat of Napoleon's army at Waterloo. But Wellington and the
British took the credit, and with it, the lion's share of world gold reserves
which subsequently flowed into London. "As good as Sterling" was the truism
of that day. After a law of June 22 1816, gold was declared the sole measure of
value in the British Empire. British foreign policy over the next 75 years or
more, would be increasingly preoccupied with securing for British coffers—the vaults
of the Bank of England--the newly mined reserves of world gold, whether in
Australia, California or in South Africa. The corollary of this minerals policy
was a policy of "strategic denial" of those same identified gold
reserves from competitor nations whenever possible.
After 1815, British naval superiority was unchallenged
on the world's seas. British ships carried British steel, coal and exports of
the Manchester textile industry. English manufactures had led the world for
decades.
But behind her apparent status as the world's pre-eminent
power, Britain was rotting internally. The more that British merchant houses
extended credit for world trade, and City of London banks funneled loan capital
to build railways in Argentina, the United States and Russia, the more the
domestic economic basis of the English nation-state deteriorated. Few
understood how ruthlessly lawful was the connection between the two parallel
processes at the time.
Since the 1814-15 Congress of Vienna, which carved up
post-Napoleonic Europe, with the diplomatic maneuvering of British Foreign
Minister Lord Castlereagh, the British Empire had exacted rights to dominate
the seas, in return for the self-serving "concessions" granted to Habsburg
Austria and the rest of Continental European powers, which concessions served
to keep central Continental Europe divided, and too weak to rival British global
expansion.
British control of the seas, and, with it, control of
world shipping trade, was thus to emerge after Waterloo as one of the three
pillars of a new British Empire. The manufactures of Continental Europe, as
well as much of the rest of the world, were forced to respond to terms of trade
set in London, by the Lloyds shipping insurance and banking syndicates. While
Her Royal Britannic Majesty's Navy, the world's largest in that day, policed
the world's major sea-lanes and provided cost-free "insurance" for
British merchant shipping vessels, competitor fleets were forced to insure
their ships against piracy, catastrophe and acts of war, through London's large
Lloyd's insurance syndicate.
Credit and bills of exchange out of the banks of the
City of London were necessary for most of the world's shipping trade finance.
The private Bank of England, itself the creature of the pre-eminent houses of
finance in London's "City" as the financial district is called--houses
such as Barings, Hambros, Rothschilds--manipulated the world's largest monetary
gold supply, in calculated actions which could cause a flood of English exports
to be dumped mercilessly onto any competitor market at will. Britain's
unquestioned domination of international banking was the second pillar of
English Imperial power following 1815.
The third pillar, more and more crucial as the century
wore on, was British geo-political domination of the world's major raw materials--cotton,
metals, coffee, coal and, by the century's end, the new "black gold,"
petroleum.
Free Trade and the Sinews of British Power
In 1820, Britain's Parliament passed a declaration of
principle which was to usher in a series of changes that had as one consequence,
outbreak almost a century later, of World War I and its tragic aftermath.
Acting on the urgings of a powerful group of London
shipping and banking interests centered around the Bank of England, and Alexander
Baring of Baring Brothers merchant bankers, Parliament passed a Statement of
Principle in support of the concept several decades earlier advocated by Scottish
economist, Adam Smith, so- called "absolute free trade."
By 1846, this declaration of principle had become
formalized in a Parliamentary repeal of domestic English agriculture protection,
the famous Corn Laws. The Corn Laws repeal was based on the calculation of
powerful financial and trade interests of the City of London, that their world
dominance gave them a decisive advantage, which they should push to the hilt.
If they dominated world trade, "free trade" could only insure their dominance
grew at the expense of other less-developed trading nations.
Under the hegemony of free trade, British merchant
banks reaped enormous profits on the India-Turkey-China opium trade, while the British
Foreign Ministry furthered their banking interests by publicly demanding China
open its ports to "free trade," during the British Opium Wars.
A new weekly propaganda journal of these powerful City
of London merchant and finance interests, The Economist, was founded in 1843
with the explicit purpose of agitating for the repeal of the Corn Laws.
The British Tory Party of Sir Robert Peel pushed
through the fateful Corn Law Repeal in May 1846, a turning point not only in British
but in world history, for the worse. Repeal opened the door for a flood of
cheap products in agriculture, which created ruin among not only English but
also other nation's farmers. The merchants simple dictum, "Buy
Cheap...Sell Dear," was raised to the level of national economic strategy.
Consumption was deemed the sole purpose of production.
Britain's domestic agriculture and farmers were ruined
by the loss of the Corn Laws protectionism. Irish farmers were enmiserated, as
their largest export market suddenly lowered food prices drastically, as a result
of Corn Law repeal. The mass starvation and out-migration of Irish peasants and
their families in the late 1840's--the tragic Irish Potato Famine of 1845-6 and
its aftermath--was a direct consequence of this "free trade" policy
of Britain. England's prior policy toward Ireland prohibited development of a
strong self-sufficient manufacture, demanding it remain the economically
captive bread basket to supply England's needs. Now that bread basket itself
was destroyed in pursuit of the fictional free trade.
After 1846, Hindu peasants from Britain's Indian
colony competed, with their dirt poor wage cost, against British and Irish farmers,
for the market of the British "consumer." Wage levels inside Britain
began falling with the price of bread. The English Poor Laws granted
compensation for workers earning below human subsistence wage, with income supplement
payment pegged to the price of a loaf of wheat bread. Thus, as bread prices
plunged, so did living standards in England.
In effect, repeal of Corn Laws protectionism opened
the floodgates throughout the British Empire to a "cheap labor policy."
The only ones to benefit, following an initial surge of cheap food prices in
England, were the giant international London trading houses, and the merchant
banks which financed them. The class separations of British society were
aggravated by a growing separation of a tiny number of very wealthy from the
growing masses of very poor, as a lawful consequence of 'free trade.'[1]
E. Peshine Smith, an American economist and fierce
opponent of British free trade, writing at the time, summarized the effect of the
British Empire's free trade hegemony over the world economy of the 1850's:
"Such has been the policy which still controls the legislation of Great
Britain. It has, in practice, regarded the nation collectively as a gigantic
trader, with the rest of the world, possessing a great stock of goods, not for
use, but for sale, endeavouring to produce them cheaply, so that it might undersell
rival shopkeepers; and looking upon the wages paid to its own people as so much
lost to the profits of the establishment."[2]
Peshine Smith contrasted this "nation as giant
shopkeeper" doctrine of the Britain of Adam Smith & company, to the
growing national economic thinking emerging on the Continent of Europe in the
1850's, especially under the German Zollverein and other national economic
policies of Friedrich List..[3]
"Their policy" Smith notes, "will be
dictated by the instincts of producers, and not that of shopkeepers. They will
look to the aggregate of production, not to the rate of profits in trade, as the
test of national prosperity. Accordingly, the great Continental nations,
France, Russia and the German States-- united in the Zollverein or Customs
Union--have practically repudiated the idea which has so long controlled the
commercial policy of England. What England has gained by that policy is thus described
by one of her own learned and respected writers, Joseph Kay, who speaks of that
nation as the one 'where the aristocracy is richer and more powerful than any
other country in the world, the poor are more oppressed, more pauperized, more
numerous in comparison to the other classes, more irreligious and very much
worse educated than the poor of any other European nation, solely excepting
uncivilized Russia and Turkey, enslaved Italy, mis-governed Portugal and
revolutionized Spain.'" [4]
So a campaign began to shape ruling English ideology
in 1851, using a viciously false Malthusian argument of over-population, rather
than admit the reality of a deliberate policy of forced under-investment in new
productive technologies. The name given the political doctrine which rationalized
the brutal economic policy, was English Liberalism. In essence, English
Liberalism, as it was defined towards the end of the 19th century, justified development
of an ever more powerful imperial elite class, ruling on behalf of the
"vulgar ignorant masses," who could not be entrusted to rule on their
own behalf.
But the underlying purpose of the liberal elites of
19th century British government and public life was to preserve and serve the interests
of an exclusive private power. In the last part of the 19th century, that
private power was concentrated in the hands of a tiny number of bankers and
institutions of the City of London.
Britain's 'Informal Empire'
Such free trade manipulation has been the essence of
British economic strategy for the past one hundred fifty years. Britain's genius
has been a chameleon-like ability to adapt that policy to a shifting
international economic reality. But the core policy has remained--Adam Smith's
"absolute free trade," as a weapon against sovereign national
economic policy of rival powers.
By the end of the 19th century, the British
establishment began an intense debate over how to maintain its global empire.
Amid slogans about a new era of "anti-imperialism," beginning the last
quarter of the 19th century, Britain embarked on a more sophisticated and far
more effective form for maintaining its dominant world role, through what came
to be called, "informal empire." While maintaining core imperial
possessions in India and the Far East, British capital flowed in prodigious
amounts into especially Argentina, Brazil and the United States, to form bonds of
financial dependence in many ways more effective than formal colonial titles.
The notion of special economic relationships with
"client states," the concept of "spheres of influence" as
well as of "balance-of-power diplomacy," all came out of this complex
weave of British "Informal Empire" towards the end of the last
century.
Since the English defeat of Spain's Armada in 1588,
Britain had used the special circumstance that it was an island apart from Continental
Europe. It was saved the costs of having to raise a large standing army to
defend its interests, leaving her free to concentrate on mastery of the seas.
Britain's looting of the wealth of the vast reaches of the world allowed her to
maintain, as well, a balance-of-power on the Continent, creating or financing
coalitions against which ever nation seemed on the verge at a given time of dominating
the European land mass stretching from Russia to Spain.
In the aftermath of the 1815 Congress of Vienna, in
the reorganized Europe following the defeat of Napoleon, England had perfected the
cynical diplomatic strategy known as "Balance of Power." Never was it
admitted by Her Majesty's Foreign Office establishment that, as on a scale,
with weights added to equalize opposite sides of a center "balance
point," British Balance of Power diplomacy was rigorously defined, always,
from the fulcrum or center point of London, that is, how England could play off
rival economic powers to unique English advantage.
After 1815, the peculiar "genius" of English
foreign policy lay in its skill, abruptly if necessary, in shifting alliance relations
as their perception of strategic power in Europe or globally shifted. English
diplomacy cultivated this cynical doctrine, which dictated that England never
held sentimental or moral relations with other nations as sovereign respected partners,
but rather, England developed her "interests." English alliance
strategies were dictated strictly by what England determined at any given
period might best serve the definition of English "interest." The
shift from hostile relations with France in Africa to England's "Entente
Cordiale" after the Fashoda showdown in 1898, or the shift from decades-long
English backing for Ottoman Turkey to block the expansion of Russia, in what
was known in Britain and India, as the "Great Game," were indicative
of such dramatic alliance shifts.
Increasingly during the last decades of the 19th
century, English capital flowed into select capital-deficit countries such as Argentina,
during the last decades of the 19th century, in order to finance, build, then
run their national rail and transport infrastructure, a role usually encouraged
by generous concessions from the host government. English capital also went to
develop the local country's steamship lines and their ports. So were the economies
of Argentina and other English "client states" effectively made into
an economic captive, with terms of trade and finance dictated from the City of
London, by British merchant houses and trade finance banks. These client states
of England thereby found that they had surrendered control over their essential
economic sovereignty far more efficiently than had British troops occupied
Buenos Aires to enforce tax collection in support of the British Empire.
During the 1880's Argentina's new railroads brought
her goods, especially beef and wheat to its ports for export. Exports doubled
and her external debts, mainly to London banks, increased 700%. The country was
a debt vassal of the British Empire, "imperialism on the cheap" as one
commentator dubbed it. It was manifestly not the intent of British policy to
develop strong sovereign industrial economies from these client state relationships.
Rather, it was to make the minimum investment necessary to control, while ensuring
other rival powers not gain coveted raw materials or other treasures of
economic power.
During this time, in order first to safeguard her sea
lanes to India, British troops occupied Egypt in 1882. The Suez Canal must not
be allowed to fall into rival French hands she reasoned. The British military
occupation so destroyed any structure of Egyptian rule that British soldiers
remained a permanent presence after 1882, in this nodal point to the spinal
cord of Empire between London and India.
Similarly, British presence in South Africa initially
was in order to safeguard the southern route to India, preventing foreign rival
powers from securing bases there which could flank British shipping trade.
British control in the 1840's and 1850's over South Africa was not formal.
Instead, Britain shut the Boer Republics from access to the Indian Ocean in
stages, beginning their annexation of Natal in 1843, keeping the Boers out of Delagoa
Bay and intervening to block the union of the Boer Republics under Pretorius in
1869. The goal was to ensure, by least means necessary, British supremacy in
the entire southern African region.
Secure monopoly for Britain's control of trade was
primary in this 19th century era of British Imperialism.
British Secret Intelligence Services in this time also
evolved in an unusual manner. Unlike the empires of France or other nations, Britain
modelled its post-Waterloo empire on an extremely sophisticated marriage
between top bankers and financiers of the City of London, Government cabinet
ministers, heads of key industrial companies deemed strategic to the national
interest, and the heads of the espionage services.
Representative of this arrangement was City of London
merchant banking scion, Sir Charles Jocelyn Hambro, who sat as a director of
the Bank of England from 1928 until his death in 1963. During the Second World
War Hambro was Executive Chief of British secret intelligence's Special Operations
Executive (SOE), inside the Government's Ministry of Economic Warfare, which ran
wartime economic warfare against Germany, and trained the entire leadership of
what was to become the postwar American Central Intelligence Agency and
intelligence elite, including William Casey, Charles Kindelberger, Walt Rostow,
Robert Roosa, later Kennedy Treasury Deputy Secretary and partner of Wall
Street's elite Brown Brothers, Harriman.
Rather than traditional service to provide data from
agents of espionage in foreign capitals, Britain's Secret Intelligence Service
head himself was part of a secret masonic-like network which wove together the
immense powers of British banking, shipping, large industry and government.
Because secret, it wielded immense power over credulous or unsuspecting foreign
economies.
This covert marriage of private commercial power with
government, in the Free Trade era after 1846, was the secret of British hegemony.
British foreign policy was based on the cultivation, not of good neighbourly
relations with allies, but rather of calculated "interests," which
could dictate shifting alliances or national allies, abruptly, if required.
The Great Depression of 1873
However, as a direct consequence of this British free
trade transformation, a deep economic depression began by the early 1870's in
England following a financial panic. The Free Trade doctrine had been premised
on the assumption that British influence could ensure that same dogma became
economic policy in all the world's major trading nations. That homogeneity was
not to be won.
Following a severe London banking panic in 1857, the
City of London banking establishment including the directors of the Bank of
England, resolved on a novel device intended to prevent future outflows of gold
from London banks. The Panic of 1857 resulted from a foreign run on the
international gold reserves held by the Bank of England. The run collapsed bank
credit in the City and across the country. In response to the crisis, the
English authorities devised a policy which resulted in a simple if dangerous
evolution of central bank practice.
The Bank of England, a private holding controlled not
by the Government at the time but rather by the financial interests of the
City, realized that if it merely raised its central bank discount or interest
rate to a sufficiently high level relative to rates in competing trading countries
which at any time might be draining Britain's gold reserves, then the drain
would cease and eventually, if rates were driven sufficiently high, gold would
again flow back into the banks of the City of London from Berlin, or New York
or Paris or Moscow.
This interest rate policy was a powerful weapon in
central banking which gave the Bank of England a decisive advantage over rivals.
No matter, that the usurious high interest rates created devastating
depressions in British manufacture or agriculture; the dominant faction in
British economic policy, increasingly after the 1846 Corn Laws repeal, was not
industry or agriculture, but finance and international trade. In order to
insure the supremacy of British international banking, those bankers were willing
to sacrifice domestic industry and investment, much as in the United States
after the Kennedy assassination in the 1960's.
But the consequences for British industry of this new
Bank of England interest rate policy came home with a vengeance with the Great
Depression which set hit Britain in 1873 and lasted until 1896.
Beginning with a financial crisis in the English
banking world, as the pyramid of foreign lending to the Americas, North and South,
for railway construction collapsed, the British Empire entered what was called
then The Great Depression. Reflecting the rising unemployment and industrial
bankruptcies of that depression, British prices collapsed in an unbroken fall
from 1873 to 1896 by almost 50% in nominal terms. Unemployment became widespread.
The lack of capital investment into British
manufactures was evident already at the International Exhibition of 1867, where
products from entirely new manufactures of machinery, even textiles from
Germany and elsewhere, clearly overshadowed the stagnant technological levels of
British manufacture, only two decades before the world leader. Export of
British iron and steel, coal and other products declined in this period. It was
a turning point in British history which signalled that the onset of "free
trade" some three decades earlier, with repeal of the Corn Laws, had
doomed English industrial technology to decadence in order that finance assume
supremacy in the affairs of the Empire.
The period of Britain's easy leadership among the
world's industrial nations, by the 1890's was clearly over.
The free trade dogma of 19th Century British Empire,and
its malthusian rationalizations, were doomed to eventual failure. Its foundations
were based on cannibalizing the economies of increasing parts of the globe in order
to survive. It was only a quarter century after the repeal of the Corn Laws
when the British Empire sank into the worst and longest economic depression of
its history as a consequence. After 1873, British efforts to spread the virus
of the "English Disease," Adam Smith's "cosmopolitan economic
model" of absolute free trade, became markedly less successful, as nations
of Continental Europe, led by Germany, initiated a series of national economic protectionist
measures which allowed them to unleash the most dramatic rates of industrial
growth seen in the past 200 years.
This all set the stage for a new debate within the
British elite over how to maintain
Empire and power in a rapidly changing world. Into this debate the geopolitics
of petroleum was introduced in 1882, in the realm of a debate on how to
maintain British naval supremacy. [5]
Endnotes:
[1] Commenting on the British free trade policy in
1851, American economist Henry C. Carey, architect of the national economic
strategy of Abraham Lincoln, noted, "We have thus here a system that is
unsound and unnatural, and second, a theory invented for the purpose of
accounting for the poverty and wretchedness which are its necessary results.
The miseries of Ireland are charged to over-population, although millions of acres
of the richest soils of the kingdom are waiting drainage to take their place
among the most productive in the world, and although the people of Ireland are
compelled to waste more labour than would pay, many times over, for all the
cloth and iron they consume...Over-population is the ready excuse for all the
evils of a vicious system, and so will it continue to be until that system
shall see its end. To maintain it, the price of labour in England must be kept
steadily at a point so low as to enable her to underwrite the Hindoo, the German,
and the American, with all the disadvantage of freight and duties."
Carey continues,
"England had monopolized machinery for so long a time that she had
acquired skill that could not readily be rivalled; while she had, by this
improper division of her population, kept the price of labour and capital at a
lower point...than among her neighbours. Her establishments were gigantic, and
always ready to sink those who might undertake competition; while the unceasing
changes in her monetary arrangements, the necessary consequences of the
colonial system, were of themselves sufficient to spread ruin among all the
nations connected with her."
Carey cites the experience of
America, with bank panics and an economic depression beginning 1837. American
credit had shifted more and more into the control of the banks of the City of
London after the 1820's, and away from List's notion of national economy.
In Britain, under the free trade
effects on labor, he notes, "Women have been substituted for men, and
children of the most immature years for women, and the hours of labour have been
so far extended as to render Parliamentary interference absolutely necessary."
He rails at the "awful consequences that have resulted from this effort to
tax the world by monopolizing machinery. The moral effects are as bad as the
physical ones.
Frauds of every kind have become almost universal.
Flour is substituted for cotton...The quality of iron and of all other commodities
is uniformly reduced to the point required for preventing other nations from
producing such commodities for themselves."
Carey cites the 1846 Corn Law
repeal as the watershed of policy: "Let us now look to the results ((of
the 1846 Corn Laws Repeal Act)) as exhibited in the immediate dependencies of England.
With this vast increase in the importation of food from abroad has come the
ruin of the people of Ireland. Deprived of manufacture and commerce, her
people were driven to live by agriculture alone, and she was enabled to drag on
a miserable existence, so long as her neighbor was content to make some
compensation for the loss of labour by paying her for her products higher
prices than those at which they might have been elsewhere purchased."
"With the repeal of the
Corn Laws, that resource has failed," Carey continues, "and the
result is a state of poverty, wretchedness and famine, that has obliged the
((Irish)) landowner to maintain the people, whether they work or not; and thus
is one of the conditions of slavery re-established in that unhappy country.
From being a great exporter of food, she has now become a large importer. The
great market for Indian corn is Ireland—a country in which the production of
food is almost the sole occupation of the people...The whole system has for its
object an increase in the number of persons that intervene between the producer
and the consumer...thus it is that Ireland is compelled to waste more labour annually
than would be required to produce, thrice over, all the iron, and convert into
cloth all the cotton and wool manufactured in England." --Carey, Henry C.
"The Harmony of Interests: Agricultural, Manufacturing &
Commercial." 1851.
Philadelphia. J.S. Skinner. pp. 60-65.
[2] Smith, E. Peshine. "A Manual of Political
Economy." 1853. New York. George P. Putnam & Co. pp. 149-152
[3] List, Friedrich. "The National System of
Political Economy." 1885 edition. London. Longmanns, Green & Co. reprinted
by Augustus M. Kelley, New York, 1966.
[4] Smith, op. Cit.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.